Difference between revisions of "Vzaimnyi zachet (Russia)"

From Global Informality Project
Jump to: navigation, search
 
(2 intermediate revisions by one other user not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{infobox
+
{{infobox  
  | nameofpractice = Vzaimnyi zachet
+
| nameofpractice =Vzaimozachety
  | location = Russia
+
| flagemoji = 🇷🇺
  | imagemap = Russia map.png
+
| definition =Russian term meaning ‘bilateral exchange in kind’, and referring to a specific type of inter-firm exchange, whereby a commodity transferred to a partner is paid for by non-monetary means.
  | imageflag = Russia flag.png
+
| location =Russia
  | authorofpiece = Caroline Dufy
+
| imagemap =Russia map.png
  | authorinstitution = Centre Emile Durkheim, Sciences Po Bordeaux, and Centre national de la recherche scientifique (CNRS)
+
| clusters =
}}
+
[[:Category:Market|Market]] – [[:Category: Functional ambivalence| Functional ambivalence]] – [[:Category: Gaming the system| Gaming the system]] – [[:Category: Camouflage| Camouflage]] – [[:Category: Creating facades| Creating facades]]
 +
| categories =
 +
[[:Category:Russia|Russia]] – [[:Category: FSU| FSU]] – [[:Category: Entrepreneurship| Entrepreneurship]] – [[:Category: Taxation| Taxation]] – [[:Category: Tax avoidance| Tax avoidance]]
 +
| authorofpiece =Caroline Dufy
 +
| authorinstitution =Centre Emile Durkheim, Sciences Po Bordeaux, France
 +
| authorwebsite =[https://durkheim.u-bordeaux.fr/Notre-equipe/Chercheur-e-s-et-enseignant-e-s-chercheur-e-s/CV/Caroline-Dufy Profile page at PO]}}
 +
<big>'''By Caroline Dufy, Centre Emile Durkheim, Sciences Po Bordeaux, France'''</big>
 +
[[Category:Market]]
 +
[[Category: Functional ambivalence]]
 +
[[Category: Gaming the system]]
 +
[[Category: Camouflage]]
 +
[[Category: Creating facades]]
 +
[[Category:Russia]]
 +
[[Category: FSU]]
 +
[[Category: Entrepreneurship]]
 +
[[Category: Taxation]]
 +
[[Category: Tax avoidance]]
 +
[[Category:Entry]]
 +
[[Category: Volume 2]]
 +
{| class="wikitable"
 +
|-
 +
|style="font-size:1.1em;"| ''Vzaimnyi zachet'' (also known as ''vzaimo zachet, zachetnaya skhema and zachet vzaimnykh'' ''trebovanii'') is a Russian term meaning ‘bilateral exchange in kind.’ When used in the plural (''vzaimnye zachety''), it refers to a specific type of inter-firm exchange, whereby a commodity transferred to a partner is paid for by non-monetary means.
  
'''''Original text: Caroline Dufy, Centre Emile Durkheim, Sciences Po Bordeaux, and Centre national de la recherche scientifique (CNRS)'''''
+
In this sense, ''vzaimnye zachety'' are
 
 
<div class="toccolours mw-collapsible mw-collapsed">
 
''Vzaimnyi zachet'' (also known as ''vzaimo zachet, zachetnaya skhema and zachet vzaimnykh''
 
''trebovanii'') is a Russian term meaning ‘bilateral exchange in kind.’ When used in the plural
 
(''vzaimnye zachety''), it refers to a specific type of inter-firm exchange, whereby a commodity
 
transferred to a partner is paid for by non-monetary means. In this sense, ''vzaimnye zachety'' are
 
 
part of a wider concept of transactions-in-kind described in Russian as barter, which in turn is
 
part of a wider concept of transactions-in-kind described in Russian as barter, which in turn is
 
derived from the English ‘barter,’ meaning the exchange of goods or services for other goods
 
derived from the English ‘barter,’ meaning the exchange of goods or services for other goods
 
or services without the use of money.
 
or services without the use of money.
 +
|}
  
<div class="mw-collapsible-content">
 
 
Non-monetary transactions are commonplace in international trade. Under the Soviet
 
Non-monetary transactions are commonplace in international trade. Under the Soviet
 
economic system, such transactions enabled socialist states such as the Soviet Union, which
 
economic system, such transactions enabled socialist states such as the Soviet Union, which
Line 44: Line 59:
 
goods, who were excluded from the hard-money circuit, to distribute and sell their goods on
 
goods, who were excluded from the hard-money circuit, to distribute and sell their goods on
 
alternative circuits, using non-monetary means of exchange<ref>Yakovlev, A. 2000. ‘Barter in the Russian Economy: Classifications and Implications
 
alternative circuits, using non-monetary means of exchange<ref>Yakovlev, A. 2000. ‘Barter in the Russian Economy: Classifications and Implications
(Evidence from Case Study Analyses),’ Post-Communist Economies 12 (3): 279-91</ref>. The second
+
(Evidence from Case Study Analyses),’ Post-Communist Economies 12 (3): 279-91</ref>.  
 +
 
 +
The second
 
denoted a complex chain of exchanges, mixing commodity-transfers and debt-schemes,
 
denoted a complex chain of exchanges, mixing commodity-transfers and debt-schemes,
 
whereby Party A transferred a commodity to Party B, who thereby became indebted to Party
 
whereby Party A transferred a commodity to Party B, who thereby became indebted to Party
Line 52: Line 69:
 
and why does it matter’ in P. Seabright, The Vanishing Rouble: Barter, Networks and Non-
 
and why does it matter’ in P. Seabright, The Vanishing Rouble: Barter, Networks and Non-
 
Monetary Transactions in Post-Soviet Russia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 93-
 
Monetary Transactions in Post-Soviet Russia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 93-
113</ref>. While the first type described above referred
+
113</ref>.  
 +
 
 +
While the first type described above referred
 
to demonetisation, the second often involved tax-evasion and the bypassing of legal
 
to demonetisation, the second often involved tax-evasion and the bypassing of legal
 
regulations. In the illegal and criminal transactions described by many experts as Russia’s
 
regulations. In the illegal and criminal transactions described by many experts as Russia’s
Line 66: Line 85:
 
organisations—such as the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank and the European
 
organisations—such as the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank and the European
 
Bank for Reconstruction and Development—which monitored the transition of the former
 
Bank for Reconstruction and Development—which monitored the transition of the former
socialist countries to a market-based economy. In his annual address to the Russian
+
socialist countries to a market-based economy.  
 +
 
 +
In his annual address to the Russian
 
parliament in 1998, President Boris Yeltsin declared that ‘The Russian market is still cluttered
 
parliament in 1998, President Boris Yeltsin declared that ‘The Russian market is still cluttered
 
with barter. It is in the stranglehold of mutual debt defaults; enterprises live on debt and have
 
with barter. It is in the stranglehold of mutual debt defaults; enterprises live on debt and have
Line 82: Line 103:
 
workings of the shadow economy<ref>Ledeneva, A. (2000). &#39;Shadow Barter: Economic Necessity or Economic Crime?&#39; in
 
workings of the shadow economy<ref>Ledeneva, A. (2000). &#39;Shadow Barter: Economic Necessity or Economic Crime?&#39; in
 
Seabright,P. (ed.) The Vanishing Rouble: Barter Networks and Non-Monetary Transactions in
 
Seabright,P. (ed.) The Vanishing Rouble: Barter Networks and Non-Monetary Transactions in
Post-Soviet Societies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 298-317.</ref>. The dramatic rise of the practice of barter
+
Post-Soviet Societies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 298-317.</ref>.  
 +
 
 +
The dramatic rise of the practice of barter
 
in Russia in the 1990s surprised Russian observers as well as many experts from international
 
in Russia in the 1990s surprised Russian observers as well as many experts from international
 
organisations<ref>Commander, S. and Mumssen C. 1998. ‘Understanding Barter in Russia.’ EBRD Working
 
organisations<ref>Commander, S. and Mumssen C. 1998. ‘Understanding Barter in Russia.’ EBRD Working
Line 88: Line 111:
 
Empirical Analysis.’ IMF Working paper, WP/OO/155
 
Empirical Analysis.’ IMF Working paper, WP/OO/155
 
https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2000/wp00155.pdf</ref>. Up until then, the socialist economy had entailed fixed prices which generated
 
https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2000/wp00155.pdf</ref>. Up until then, the socialist economy had entailed fixed prices which generated
shortages, informal exchanges and a lack of competitiveness. In 1991, when Russia began its
+
shortages, informal exchanges and a lack of competitiveness.  
 +
 
 +
In 1991, when Russia began its
 
transition to a market economy, prices started fluctuating, thereby reflecting the volatile
 
transition to a market economy, prices started fluctuating, thereby reflecting the volatile
 
desirability of goods. Pro-market advocates see the monetisation of transactions in the
 
desirability of goods. Pro-market advocates see the monetisation of transactions in the
Line 102: Line 127:
 
default on its external debt led however to a dramatic drop in barter, which in 2001 and 2002
 
default on its external debt led however to a dramatic drop in barter, which in 2001 and 2002
 
fell to a low of 16 percent of industrial sales<ref>Russian Economic Barometer. 2003. 1: 24
 
fell to a low of 16 percent of industrial sales<ref>Russian Economic Barometer. 2003. 1: 24
http://www.imemo.ru/files/File/magazines/REB_kvartal/2003/2003_01_reb_kvartal_ru.pdf</ref>. Following
+
http://www.imemo.ru/files/File/magazines/REB_kvartal/2003/2003_01_reb_kvartal_ru.pdf</ref>.  
 +
 
 +
Following
 
the 1998 crisis, the Russian government tasked the State Statistics Committee with measuring
 
the 1998 crisis, the Russian government tasked the State Statistics Committee with measuring
 
the various means of transaction used by businesses. Their findings revealed a steady decline
 
the various means of transaction used by businesses. Their findings revealed a steady decline
Line 119: Line 146:
 
Cambridge University Press</ref><ref>Humphrey, C. and Hugh-Jones S. (eds) 1992. Barter, exchange and value: An
 
Cambridge University Press</ref><ref>Humphrey, C. and Hugh-Jones S. (eds) 1992. Barter, exchange and value: An
 
anthropological approach. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press</ref>. This provides a basis with which to explain
 
anthropological approach. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press</ref>. This provides a basis with which to explain
the negative appraisal in relation to the norms and models implemented by society. The
+
the negative appraisal in relation to the norms and models implemented by society.  
 +
 
 +
The
 
British economist William Stanley Jevons defined barter as a situation requiring a ‘double
 
British economist William Stanley Jevons defined barter as a situation requiring a ‘double
 
coincidence of wants’<ref>Jevons, W. 1875. Money and the Mechanism of Exchange. Available on-line at
 
coincidence of wants’<ref>Jevons, W. 1875. Money and the Mechanism of Exchange. Available on-line at
Line 128: Line 157:
 
as to the quality of the goods received, and confusion over the return deadline<ref>Dufy, C. 2008. Le Troc dans le marché: pour une sociologie des échanges dans la Russie
 
as to the quality of the goods received, and confusion over the return deadline<ref>Dufy, C. 2008. Le Troc dans le marché: pour une sociologie des échanges dans la Russie
 
post-soviétique. Paris: L’Harmattan</ref>.
 
post-soviétique. Paris: L’Harmattan</ref>.
 +
 
As shown by the history of the rise and fall of ''vzaimnye zachety'', the definition of transactions
 
As shown by the history of the rise and fall of ''vzaimnye zachety'', the definition of transactions
 
is at the heart of economic and social design. For, as the cornerstones are being laid in the
 
is at the heart of economic and social design. For, as the cornerstones are being laid in the
 
burgeoning market, these definitions make a clear-cut distinction between those types of
 
burgeoning market, these definitions make a clear-cut distinction between those types of
 
transactions that are considered desirable, and those that are not.
 
transactions that are considered desirable, and those that are not.
</div>
+
 
</div>
+
==References==
==Notes==
 
 
<references />
 
<references />
'''Further reading:'''<br>
+
 
 +
==Further reading==
 
Aukutsionek, S. 1994. ‘Barter in Russian industry,’ Russian Economic Barometer 3: 3-13<br>
 
Aukutsionek, S. 1994. ‘Barter in Russian industry,’ Russian Economic Barometer 3: 3-13<br>
 
Aukutsionek, S. 1997. ‘Industrial Barter in Russia,’ Russian Economic Barometer 3: 3-17<br>
 
Aukutsionek, S. 1997. ‘Industrial Barter in Russia,’ Russian Economic Barometer 3: 3-17<br>
Line 159: Line 189:
 
Woodruff, D. 1999b. Money Unmade: Barter and the Fate of Russian Capitalism. Ithaca:
 
Woodruff, D. 1999b. Money Unmade: Barter and the Fate of Russian Capitalism. Ithaca:
 
Cornell University Press
 
Cornell University Press
 
[[Category:Entry]]
 
[[Category:Russia]]
 

Latest revision as of 15:41, 29 September 2019

Vzaimozachety 🇷🇺
Russia map.png
Location: Russia
Definition: Russian term meaning ‘bilateral exchange in kind’, and referring to a specific type of inter-firm exchange, whereby a commodity transferred to a partner is paid for by non-monetary means.
Keywords: Russia FSU Entrepreneurship Taxation Tax avoidance
Clusters: Market Functional ambivalence Gaming the system Camouflage Creating facades
Author: Caroline Dufy
Affiliation: Centre Emile Durkheim, Sciences Po Bordeaux, France
Website: Profile page at PO

By Caroline Dufy, Centre Emile Durkheim, Sciences Po Bordeaux, France

Vzaimnyi zachet (also known as vzaimo zachet, zachetnaya skhema and zachet vzaimnykh trebovanii) is a Russian term meaning ‘bilateral exchange in kind.’ When used in the plural (vzaimnye zachety), it refers to a specific type of inter-firm exchange, whereby a commodity transferred to a partner is paid for by non-monetary means.

In this sense, vzaimnye zachety are part of a wider concept of transactions-in-kind described in Russian as barter, which in turn is derived from the English ‘barter,’ meaning the exchange of goods or services for other goods or services without the use of money.

Non-monetary transactions are commonplace in international trade. Under the Soviet economic system, such transactions enabled socialist states such as the Soviet Union, which lacked access to foreign-currency reserves, to pay for imported goods. Trade between the member-states of the Soviet-led Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (COMECON), for example, was mostly handled through countertrade or bilateral clearing agreements. For instance, the German Democratic Republic supplied the USSR with machinery and in exchange the USSR supplied it with oil.

Following the collapse of the USSR, vzaimnye zachety came in the 1990s to be seen by Russian economists as a specific feature of domestic barter in the context of a dire financial and monetary crisis during which money surrogates and inter-enterprise arrears were widespread[1]. Massive arrears in wages, pensions and welfare benefits paralysed the economy at every level. Demonetisation and the disrupted role of money as a universal means of exchange made vzaimnye zachety an alternative means of enabling goods to circulate in the economy[2].

While vzaimnye zachety took many different forms, two major types may be identified. The first denoted successive bilateral exchanges, whereby one original entity exchanged goods or money surrogates in successive bilateral transactions with several partners until the desired commodity was attained. This strategy allowed holders of low-value goods, who were excluded from the hard-money circuit, to distribute and sell their goods on alternative circuits, using non-monetary means of exchange[3].

The second denoted a complex chain of exchanges, mixing commodity-transfers and debt-schemes, whereby Party A transferred a commodity to Party B, who thereby became indebted to Party A. The commodity was then transferred to Party C, who in turn became indebted to Party B, and so on. The chain might involve five, six or even more parties in debt-and delayed- payment chains[4].

While the first type described above referred to demonetisation, the second often involved tax-evasion and the bypassing of legal regulations. In the illegal and criminal transactions described by many experts as Russia’s ‘virtual economy’[5][6][7], intermediate firms were often artificially bankrupted; this meant that, while the original supplier went unpaid, the final recipient took possession of a commodity that had no owner needing to be paid for it.

High negative moral value was accordingly attributed to vzaimnye zachety by economists, officials and experts from international economic and financial organisations—such as the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank and the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development—which monitored the transition of the former socialist countries to a market-based economy.

In his annual address to the Russian parliament in 1998, President Boris Yeltsin declared that ‘The Russian market is still cluttered with barter. It is in the stranglehold of mutual debt defaults; enterprises live on debt and have no intention of repaying their debts… This practice cannot be continued. It is useless and dangerous to try to cheat the economy’[8].

Vzaimnye zachety have been criticised by economists and officials on several grounds. The first concerns the discrepancy between barter and economic norms in modern capitalism, while the second relates to a loophole in the legal conditions of exchange. Anthropologists have also noted the phenomenon of ‘shadow barter,’ that is, the close association between the ingenuous schemes of barter exchanges justified by economic necessity and the illegal workings of the shadow economy[9].

The dramatic rise of the practice of barter in Russia in the 1990s surprised Russian observers as well as many experts from international organisations[10][11]. Up until then, the socialist economy had entailed fixed prices which generated shortages, informal exchanges and a lack of competitiveness.

In 1991, when Russia began its transition to a market economy, prices started fluctuating, thereby reflecting the volatile desirability of goods. Pro-market advocates see the monetisation of transactions in the economy as encouraging efficiency, favouring the emergence of interest-based behaviour and, more generally, paving the way for further structural changes. This was not, however, the case in Russia. Far from declining as expected in the new market conditions, the share of barter in commodity-exchanges grew dramatically. In 1993, barter was estimated to account for a mere 9 percent of the volume of industrial sales in Russia. Within three years, however, its share nearly quadrupled, reaching 35 percent in 1996, 42 percent in 1997 and 51 percent in 1998[12][13].

The financial crisis of August 1998, the sharp devaluation of the rouble and Russia’s default on its external debt led however to a dramatic drop in barter, which in 2001 and 2002 fell to a low of 16 percent of industrial sales[14].

Following the 1998 crisis, the Russian government tasked the State Statistics Committee with measuring the various means of transaction used by businesses. Their findings revealed a steady decline in barter. In 1999, 47.4 percent of all transactions were based on non-monetary means of payment, 24.5 percent of which were vzaimnye zachety. In 2000, barter accounted for only 30.2 percent of all transactions, 15.5 percent of which were vzaimnye zachety. The massive devaluation of the rouble in 1998 had reduced arrears in the economy and remonetised transactions. Russia’s competitiveness increased, easing exports and reducing the flow of imports. In the 2000s, a process of legislation and accounting-regulation effectively banned barter in Russia, leaving only bilateral exchanges in kind[15][16].

Classic economic anthropology highlights the moral value of transactions[17][18]. This provides a basis with which to explain the negative appraisal in relation to the norms and models implemented by society.

The British economist William Stanley Jevons defined barter as a situation requiring a ‘double coincidence of wants’[19]. In support of his argument, multiple testimonies collected in fieldwork in Russia in the early 2000s depicted barter as a less than optimal situation, requiring additional work to negotiate which commodities were to be accepted as means of payment. Furthermore, barter generated an imbalance between parties, uncertainty as to the quality of the goods received, and confusion over the return deadline[20].

As shown by the history of the rise and fall of vzaimnye zachety, the definition of transactions is at the heart of economic and social design. For, as the cornerstones are being laid in the burgeoning market, these definitions make a clear-cut distinction between those types of transactions that are considered desirable, and those that are not.

References

  1. Yakovlev, A. 1999. ‘O prichinax bartera, neplatezhei, i ukloneniya ot uplaty nalogov v Rossiikoi ekonomike,’ Voprosy ekonomiki 4: 102-15
  2. Marin, D. 2002. ‘Trust versus illusion; what is driving demonetization in the former Soviet Union,’ Economics of Transition 10 (1): 173-200
  3. Yakovlev, A. 2000. ‘Barter in the Russian Economy: Classifications and Implications (Evidence from Case Study Analyses),’ Post-Communist Economies 12 (3): 279-91
  4. Ledeneva, A. and Seabright, P. 2000. ‘Barter in post-Soviet societies: what does it look like and why does it matter’ in P. Seabright, The Vanishing Rouble: Barter, Networks and Non- Monetary Transactions in Post-Soviet Russia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 93- 113
  5. Gaddy, C. and Ickes, B. 1998.’Russia’s Virtual Economy,’ Foreign Affairs 77 (4): 53-67
  6. Woodruff, D. 1999a. ‘It's Value That's Virtual: Bartles, Rubles and the Place of Gazprom in the Russian Economy,’ Post-Soviet Affairs 15 (2): 130-48
  7. Tompson, W. 1999. ‘The price of everything and the value of nothing? Unravelling the workings of Russia's “virtual economy”,’ Economy and Society 28 (2): 256-80
  8. Yeltsin, B. 1998. Annual Address to the Russian Parliament. http://www.intelros.ru/2007/02/05/poslanie_prezidenta_rosii_borisa_elcina_federalnomu_sob raniju_rf_obshhimi_silami__k_podemu_rossii_1998_god.html; see also http://edition.cnn.com/WORLD/9802/17/yeltsin.russia.excerpts/
  9. Ledeneva, A. (2000). 'Shadow Barter: Economic Necessity or Economic Crime?' in Seabright,P. (ed.) The Vanishing Rouble: Barter Networks and Non-Monetary Transactions in Post-Soviet Societies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 298-317.
  10. Commander, S. and Mumssen C. 1998. ‘Understanding Barter in Russia.’ EBRD Working Paper No 7: 37
  11. Commander, S., Dolinskaya I. and Mumssen C. 2000. ‘Determinants of Barter in Russia. An Empirical Analysis.’ IMF Working paper, WP/OO/155 https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2000/wp00155.pdf
  12. Russian Economic Barometer. 2001. 4: 24 http://www.imemo.ru/jour/PEBq
  13. Aukutsionek, S. 2001. ‘Barter, New Data and Comments,’ Journal of East-West Business 6 (4): 23-35
  14. Russian Economic Barometer. 2003. 1: 24 http://www.imemo.ru/files/File/magazines/REB_kvartal/2003/2003_01_reb_kvartal_ru.pdf
  15. Efimova, L. 1997. ‘Pravovye problemy beznalichnykh deneg,’ Khozyaistvo i pravo 2: 28-49 http://www.twirpx.com/file/693311/
  16. Dufy, C. 2011. ‘Pratiques informelles dans le changement de système en Russie: entre criminalité et normalisation,’ in L. Fontaine and F. Weber (eds), Quatre paradoxes sur l’économie informelle. Paris: Karthala: 51-70
  17. Parry, J. and Bloch, M. (eds) 1989. Money and the Morality of Exchange. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
  18. Humphrey, C. and Hugh-Jones S. (eds) 1992. Barter, exchange and value: An anthropological approach. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
  19. Jevons, W. 1875. Money and the Mechanism of Exchange. Available on-line at http://oll.libertyfund.org/titles/jevons-money-and-the-mechanism-of-exchange
  20. Dufy, C. 2008. Le Troc dans le marché: pour une sociologie des échanges dans la Russie post-soviétique. Paris: L’Harmattan

Further reading

Aukutsionek, S. 1994. ‘Barter in Russian industry,’ Russian Economic Barometer 3: 3-13
Aukutsionek, S. 1997. ‘Industrial Barter in Russia,’ Russian Economic Barometer 3: 3-17
Aukutsionek, S. 1998. ‘Industrial Barter in Russia,’ Communist Economies and Economic Transformation 10 (2): 179-88
Humphrey, C. 1985. ‘Barter and Economic Disintegration,’ Man 20 (1): 48-72
Klyamkin, I. and Timofeev, L. (eds) 2000. Tenevaya Rossiya. Moscow: Russian State University for the Humanities (RGGU)
Klistorin, V. and Tcherkaskii, V. 1997. ‘Denezhnie Surrogati: Ekonomicheskie i social'nie posledstviya,’ Voprosy ekonomiki 10: 52-7 http://vopreco.ru/rus/archive.files/n10_1997.html#sr1
Makarov, V. and Kleiner, G. 1999. ‘Barter v Rossii: institutsionnal’nii etap’ Voprosy ekonomiki 4: 79-101 http://www.vopreco.ru/rus/archive.files/n4_1999.html
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2002. Measuring the Non-Observed Economy. Paris: OECD
Poser, J. 1998. ‘Monetary Disruptions and the Emergence of Barter in FSU Economies,’ Communist Economies and Economic Transformation 10 (2): 157-77
Radaev, V. 2002. ‘Entrepreneurial strategies and the structure of transactions costs in Russian business,’ Problems of Economic Transition 44 (2): 57-84
Yakovlev, A. 2002. ‘Ekonomika “chernogo nala” v Rossii: spetsifika i masshtaby yavleniya, otsenka obshchestvennykh poter,’ Voprosy statistiki 8: 3-16
Woodruff, D. 1999b. Money Unmade: Barter and the Fate of Russian Capitalism. Ithaca: Cornell University Press